Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan multi-pillar pension system - Núm. 83, Julio 2019 - Revista Desarrollo y Sociedad - Libros y Revistas - VLEX 830595673

Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan multi-pillar pension system

AutorGioia de Melo, Nicolás Castiñeiras, Analía Ardente, Oriana Montti, Braulio Zelko, Federico Araya
Páginas105-144
105
DESARRO. SOC. 71, PRIMER SEMESTRE DE 2013, PP. X-XX, ISSN 0120-3584
Revista
Desarrollo y Sociedad
83
Segundo semestre 2019
PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584
E-ISSN 1900-7760
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates
in the Uruguayan multi-pillar pension system
Elegibilidad para el retiro y tasas de reemplazo
en el sistema previsional multi-pilar en Uruguay
Gioia de Melo1
Nicolás Castiñeiras 2
Analía Ardente3
Oriana Montti4
Braulio Zelko5
Federico Araya6
DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
Abstract
We project the levels of eligibility and gross replacement rates of the pay-as-
you-go and individual capitalization pillars in Uruguay. Based on a random
sample of worker administrative records, we estimate years of contributions,
formal income, and the evolution of the individual savings fund. Our results
suggest that while 51% would be eligible for retirement at age 60, 28% would
not be able to retire from the contributory system even at age seventy. We
expect that 34% of those retiring at age 60 will receive a minimum pension
1 Organización para la Cooperación y el Desarrollo Económico, Correo electrónico: Gioia.DEMELO@ocde.org
2 Uruguay XXI, Correo electrónico: ncastineirascassanello@gmail.com
3 Ministerio de Economía y Finanzas, Correo electrónico: aardente@tgn.gub.uy
4 Ministerio de Economía y Finanzas, Correo electrónico: oriana.montti@mef.gub.uy
5 Ministerio de Economía y Finanzas, Correo electrónico: braulio.zelko@mef.gub.uy
6 Ministerio de Trabajo y Seguridad Social, Correo electrónico: faraya@mtss.gub.uy
Este artículo fue recibido el 11 de septiembre del 2018, revisado el 8 de abril del 2019 y finalmente
aceptado el 14 de junio del 2019.
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
106
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
while the replacement rate is estimated to be 52% relative to the previous
year’s wage. We conclude that Uruguay still faces challenges regarding indivi-
duals’ density of contributions and amounts declared as both reduce eligibility
levels and impose financial pressure on the pay-as-you-go pillar.
Keywords by author: Informality, pay-as-you-go, individual savings, minimum
pension, Uruguay.
JEL Classification: H55, J26, J46.
Resumen
Este artículo proyecta los niveles de elegibilidad y las tasas de reemplazo brutas
de los pilares de reparto y capitalización individual en Uruguay. A partir de una
muestra aleatoria de registros administrativos de trabajadores se proyectan los
años de servicio, los ingresos formales y la evolución del fondo de capitalización
individual. Se estima que 51% de los trabajadores generaría causal de reparto a los
setenta años, mientras que 28% no lo lograría ni siquiera a los setenta años.
Los resultados sugieren que 34% de los que se retiren a los setenta años percibirán
la jubilación mínima en tanto que la tasa de reemplazo promedio en relación con
el ingreso del último año sería de 52%. Se concluye que Uruguay aún enfrenta
desafíos en materia de densidad de contribuciones y de montos declarados que
impactan tanto en los niveles de elegibilidad como en la presión financiera
que registra el pilar de reparto.
Palabras clave del autor: informalidad, reparto, capitalización, jubilación
mínima, Uruguay.
Clasificación JEL: H55, J26, J46.
The purpose of this study is to project eligibility and replacement rates for the
Uruguayan social security system in its two pillars: mandatory individual sav-
ing accounts (defined-contribution) and the pay-as-you-go system (defined-
benefit), which expresses them as a ratio of the last salary and the average
working-life earnings. We aim to analyze both the coverage of the system and
its ability to smooth consumption over its life cycle. Bucheli, Ferreira-Coimbra,
Forteza & Rossi (2006) and Bucheli, Forteza, & Rossi (2010) estimate eligibility
prior to the 2008 law (18395) that loosened access requirements to contribu-
tory pensions. This study updates projections for the percentage of individuals
Gioia de Melo
et al.
107
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
expected to become eligible for contributive pensions and most importantly, for
the first time, estimates replacement rates for Uruguay using individual data
from social security records. Studies that project pension replacement rates
using administrative data are extremely scarce in the international literature.
Using individual data is relevant because it allows us to analyze distributive
implications and is of particular importance in countries with non-negligible
levels of informality as most countries in Latin America.
Our data consists of a random sample of 14,207 contributors to the Banco
de Previsión Social (Uruguay’s major social security agency) who in January
2017 were between 40 and 60 years old. Based on this sample, we estimate
the probability of them contributing each month until they reach retire-
ment age. We then model individual earnings based on personal characteris-
tics and macroeconomic variables. We also project the accumulated fund in
the mandatory individual savings account (FAP for its Spanish acronym). The
high quality of the data used enables us to analyze heterogeneity among
the cohort under study.
We compute gross replacement rates that result from considering both the
defined benefit and the individual savings pillar as a whole (which we name
joint replacement rate) and also analyze the replacement rate yielded by each
pillar separately and simulate how different macroeconomic scenarios affect
our results. We analyze the correlation of the resulting rates in terms of gen-
der, age cohort, average density of contributions, income quintiles, and sector
of activity. Furthermore, we examine how the rate of return of the pensions
funds’ investments and management fees affect the final amount accumu-
lated in the individual savings account and, subsequently, the annuity. Finally,
for those individuals who have a high contribution density, we analyze the
impact of postponing the decision to retire until age 65.
The paper is organized as follows: the next section describes the Uruguayan
pension system. Section II reviews the related literature. Sections III and IV
describe the sources of information and methodology used. Section V presents
the results while section VI concludes.
I. The Uruguayan pension system
In 1996, the Uruguayan pension system administered by Banco de Prevision
Social (BPS) was transformed into a “Mixed System” (Law 16713) with two
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
108
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
pillars: a pay-as-you-go (PAYG) or defined benefit scheme and an individual
savings accounts or defined contribution scheme. The system became com-
pulsory for those under 40 as of April 1, 1996. A monthly earnings threshold
separates the two pillars. Individuals with monthly wages lower than $5,000
(Uruguayan pesos in May 1995, approximately USD 1,700 in 2017) are served
by the PAYG unless they explicitly choose to participate in the individual savings
scheme. They can choose to assign 50% of their monthly contributions to the
individual savings account (Article 8 Law 16,713). If they do, BPS grants a bonus
and increases the individuals’ contributions to a defined benefit scheme by
50%. Earnings between $5,000 and $15,000 (Uruguayan pesos in May 1995)
must contribute to the individual account; it is optional to do so for earnings
above this amount.
Within the PAYG pillar, a minimum of 30 years’ contributions is required in
order to be eligible (the minimum was set at 35 in 1995 and then reduced by
Law 18,395 in 2008). Required years of contribution decrease if individuals
retire at older ages (minimum of 15 years after 70). Women benefit from one
year’s contribution per child (maximum of five years). The benefit not only
improves eligibility conditions but also increases the replacement rate of the
defined benefit scheme.
In the PAYG pillar, the earnings considered to calculate the pension are the
average wage earned in the last 10 years. Depending on what is more beneficial
for the worker, the average wage earned in the best twenty years (increased
by 5%) may also be used. The rate applied is 45% and there is an additional
1% for every extra year’s contribution between 30 and 35. For thirty-six years
of contributions onwards, every additional year worked adds 0.5% to the rate
(there is a maximum of 2.5%). Moreover, for each year that the person post-
pones retirement after the age of 60 (whether s/he continues working or not)
the replacement rate increases by two pecentage points. Therefore if an indi-
vidual reaches age 60 with 30 years’ contributions and decides to continue
working until 61, 48% will be used to calculate their pension.
As for the individual savings pillar, Law 16,713 created AFAPs that administer
the savings fund (Fondo de Ahorro Previsional) that consists of the mandatory
and voluntary workers´ contributions and its returns. AFAPs charge an admin-
istration fee and deduct an insurance premium (“Prima de Seguro Colectivo”)
that covers the risks of disability and mortality during working life. The annuity
Gioia de Melo
et al.
109
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
depends on the final accumulated fund in the individual account, sex, and age
at the time of retirement (which reflect the individuals´ life expectancy) and
the probability of having a member of the family who can claim the pension
as well as a technical interest rate. Individuals can cash their annuity when
they retire from the PAYG system or at a minimum of 65.
II. Related literature
To the best of our knowledge, only one study from Chile projects pension
replacement rates using administrative data. Berstein, Larrain and Pino, (2006)
estimate the probability of future contributions using a probit model with
random effects and an earnings model that includes individual characteris-
tics and variables related to the macroeconomic context. Replacement rates
are estimated at 121% of the average salary during the entire working life
and 44% of the last salary. Paredes and Díaz Fuchs (2013), in turn, calculate
replacement rates for Chile using the administrative data of individuals who
had already retired in 2012. They estimate an average replacement rate for the
old age pension (with at least 10 years’ contributions) of 76%. They additionally
highlight the substantial differences due to gender and contribution densities.
OECD (2013) simulates replacement rates assuming individuals contribute
to social security for 40 years earning the average wage in their respec-
tive country. For OECD member countries, the average gross replacement
rate is estimated at 54%. Durán Valverde and Pena (2011) project replace-
ment rates from the individual savings account systems of different Latin
American countries using information from household surveys. In the case of
Uruguay, they estimate replacement rates of 43% and 44% for men and wo-
men, respectively, relative to the last wage and 39% and 38% for men and
women relative to the average income of the last 20 years they worked. Forteza
and Ourens (2012) analyze the characteristics of several Latin American pen-
sion programs evaluating their impact on income inequality, insurance, and
incentives to work. They simulate lifetime contributions and benefits and con-
clude that most programs are progressive while implicit rates of return exhibit
marked discontinuities in the length of service, which they attribute to vest-
ing period conditions. A recent study by Altamirano, Berstein, Bosch, García-
Huitrón and Oliveri, (2018) analyzes pension systems across Latin America and
the Caribbean and consider hypothetical individuals with a perfect contribution
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
110
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
record in the baseline scenario. For Uruguay, the estimate for the average
replacement rate is 72% in the baseline scenario.
In contrast to the lack of studies that project replacement rates and eligibility
while using individual administrative records, there is a greater abundance of
literature that forecasts pension eligibility in Uruguay. Bucheli et al., (2010)
estimate the proportion of workers who would gain access to a pension at
the normal retirement age by using a random sample of work history records
for individuals between 18 and 70 who contributed for at least one month
between April 1996 and December 2004. They use survival analysis to model
transitions between contributing and not contributing and then apply the esti-
mated transition rates to project worker trajectories using Monte Carlo simu-
lations. Their main findings suggest that, as workers spend more time in any
of the two states (contributing or not contributing), their chances of remain-
ing in the same state increases. They also find that young workers are more
dynamic and have a higher probability of leaving either of both states. They
project that only 41.3% of workers will have accumulated 30 years’ contribu-
tions at age 60. Also, they find very significant differences between income
quintiles. It should be noted this study was carried out prior to the 2008 reform
that relaxed pension eligibility requirements.
Forteza and Sanroman (2015) estimate a structural life-cycle model for retire-
ment behavior using work history records. They find that individuals, espe-
cially women, prefer not to postpone retirement. They also find that retirement
decisions are not particularly responsive to changes in retirement modifica-
tion rules. More recently, Lavalleja, Rossi and Tenenbaum (2018) have studied
the impact of the latest legal modification in pension requirements that was
passed in 2008 using administrative records. Following Bucheli et al. (2006),
they divide the sample into groups that consider sex, income level, and con-
tribution sector and estimate the probability of contributing by group (con-
ditional on the previous month’s contribution status). Subsequently, they
simulate each group’s contribution history by using Markov chains. They con-
clude that for the minimum age of retirement (60), 38% of workers would be
eligible for retirement under the current legislation compared to 11% under
the 1996 regime (Law 16,713): a scenario in which the minimum years’ con-
tributions had not been reduced from 35 to 30 and there was no bonus year
per child for women.
Gioia de Melo
et al.
111
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
Regarding other Regarding other estimates of pensions adequacy in Uruguay,
Forteza and Rossi (2016) simulate theoretical pensions and replacement rates
for those in their 50s in 2016 and compare them with those who retired from
the PAYG system under the conditions prior to the 1996 reform. They conclude
that some individuals in their 50s (mainly high-income) would have received
a higher pension under the system prior to the reform. Alvarez, Silva, Forteza
and Rossi (2010) focus on retirement incentives by comparing the PAYG sys-
tem prior to the 1996 reform with the multi-pillar system. Using simulations
for hypothetical individuals, they conclude that the 1996 reform improved the
incentives to postpone retirement, but the incentives are still low compared
to developed countries.
III. Data
This study uses a random sample of 14,207 workers´ administrative records for
individuals aged between 40 - 60 years old as of January 2017 who contrib-
uted at least once as a dependent worker between 1996 and 2015. Using the
Longitudinal Survey of Social Protection (2015), we estimate that the sam-
ple analyzed is representative of 73% of the age bracket (with the remaining
20% never contributing to social security and 7% contributing to other pen-
sion systems). The rest of the cohort either never made contributions to social
security or made contributions to other schemes such as military, police, or
professional ones. We concentrate on this age cohort because, given the policy
debate that took place in 2016 – 2017, we were interested in comparing the
fate of those in their 50s, which was the first cohort about to retire from the
multi-pillar system, with those 10 years younger. It should also be noted that
no administrative records exist prior to 1996. The following table presents the
descriptive statistics of the variables included in the database.
Figure 1 shows the distribution of the average contribution density for the
employment history sample over the observed period (1996-2015). We observe
a significant disparity in individuals’ contribution density. In the lower distri-
bution tail, 31.6% of men and 26.9% of women contributed up to 30% in the
1996-2015 period, which is equivalent to a maximum of six years’ contribu-
tions of the 20 years considered. Moreover, approximately 25% persistently
contributed (100%) during the period. It is also important to note that slightly
less than 10% of the sample shows a contribution density of less than or equal
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
112
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
Table 1. Descriptive statistics
Variables Mean
Gender
Men 0.52
Women 0.48
Monthly income a ($ Jan-17) 26,891
Standard deviation (35,777)
Age (Jan-17) 49.2
Contribution density 0.57
Opted for Art. 8 Lay 16,713 0,60
Contribution sector
Industry and Commerce 0.63
Public servants 0.13
Rural 0.12
Construction 0.06
Housekeeping Service 0.06
Cohort
40 to 44 Cohort 0.28
45 to 49 Cohort 0.25
50 to 54 Cohort 0.23
55 to 60 Cohort 0.24
Sector
Agriculture 0.13
Manufacturing Ind. 0.13
Electricity, gas, and water 0.02
Construction 0.07
Commerce, restaurants and hotels 0.19
Transport and Communications 0.07
Financial intermediation, insurance. 0.05
Administrative Act. 0.03
Public Administration 0.11
Education 0.03
Health 0.06
Arts and others 0.04
Home Serv. 0.07
Extraterritorial Org. 0
Quintiles a
Quintile 1 4,023
Quintile 2 9,408
Quintile 3 13,699
Quintile 4 21,823
Quintile 5 55,265
Source: Authors’ own calculations based on social security records. a) Income for 1996 - 2015 at January 2017
prices in Uruguayan pesos.
Gioia de Melo
et al.
113
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
to 5%, which means that they contributed to social security for at most 12
months between 1996 - 2015. This polarization in terms of contribution density
highlights the importance of analyzing eligibility and replacement rates for the
different segments of the distribution. The percentage of workers who did not
contribute to the savings accounts pillar is estimated to be 32%. Indeed, even
if approximately 75% of the workers are situated in the first income bracket,
where contributions to the savings account are not compulsory, 60% of the
sample opted for Article 8 of Law 16713, which enables voluntary contribu-
tions to the individual savings pillar.
Figure 1. Distribution of the observed contribution density by gender (1996-2015)
Male Female
30%
25%
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%
0.05
0.95
0.90
0.85
0.80
0.75
0.70
0.65
0.60
0.55
0.50
0.45
0.40
0.35
0.30
0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
1
We define contribution density as the relationship between the number of periods contributed by the
employee to the social security system and potential contributions during his or her working life.
Source: Authors´ own computations derived from social security data.
IV. Methodology
A. Contribution density and years of contributions
To project the contribution density, we model the probability of making monthly
contributions to the social security system from 1996 onwards using a pro-
bit model with random effects including both individual characteristics and
macroeconomic indicators.
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
114
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
Let
yit
be the unobserved propensity of individual i contributing to social secu-
rity in month t, while
yit
is the observed contribution status of individual i in
month t.
yit iiti
*
 =+ +++
∝β βββ
12 13 4
Female AccumDensity Cohort Sectoor Age
InformalityFemalePar
ii
t
tt
GDP

++
++
β
ββ
6
2
8 9 tticipationtit
 
+ε(1)
yit
=1
if yit
*.>06 and 0 otherwise.
In line with Bernstein et al. (2006) and Castañeda, Castro, Céspedes and Fajn-
zylber, (2013) we fit a random effects model, where
it it i
vu=+
and
vit
and
are independent random variables and [
E
it
|
X
()
=
0]
]. Hence, the individual-
specific effects
vi
are assumed to be uncorrelated with the regressors and
constant through time.
The explanatory variables of the model are: female, the individual’s cumulative
average contribution density, generation cohort dummies, main contribution
sector dummies, age, age squared; and the following are the macroeconomic
variables: evolution of GDP, informality rate, female participation rate, and
the interaction between female and female participation rate.
The cumulative average contribution density, for each period t and for each
individual i is the ratio between the number of months that the person actu-
ally contributed to social security as a dependent worker in the period from
April 1996 to t-1, over the total number of months in the same period. We
define the binary cohort variables by age groups as of January 2017 from 40
to 44 years old (omitted category), 45 to 49 years old, 50 to 54 years old, and
55 to 60 years old. The contribution sector dummy variables follow the social
security agency´s categories: Industry and Commerce (omitted category), Pub-
lic, Construction, Rural, and Housekeeping Services.
Various specifications of the model were estimated. The final specification was
the one that best predicted the evolution observed in the 2011 - 2015 period
and yielded a reasonable evolution from 2016 onwards.7 Under our preferred
specification of a variable that reflects past contributions, that is, including
7 Indicators such as the last month or average contribution density of the last twelve months lead to
slightly higher percentages of correctly predicted observations than the cumulative average contribu-
tions density (83, 78, and 77 %, respectively). However, when extended to 2016 onwards, they tend to
forecast a steep increase in the average contribution density that is unlikely to take place given that in
the 2004 – 2014 period many policies that encouraged formalization were implemented and GDP grew
at rates above 3%. These are two features that we do not expect to prevail in our baseline scenario.
Gioia de Melo
et al.
115
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
the individual’s cumulative average contribution density, the model correctly
predicts 77% of the observations in the 2011 – 2015 period.
We should mention that not including a variable that has past information on
the individual’s contributive behavior only predicts 51% of observations cor-
rectly, which reinforces the idea that past contribution is a key regressor to
accurately forecast future. We subsequently applied a threshold to translate
the predicted probabilities. We selected a threshold of 0.6 by also testing which
was the best predictor in the sample period (2011 - 2015). The projection of
the density of contributions results from multiplying the explanatory variables
by the coefficients estimated in the probit model in table A.1 in the Appendix.
It is worth noting that given that the modelling objective is to achieve the
best possible projection and not to explain the role of a certain variable of
interest on the probability of contributing to social security, the endogene-
ity considerations of the explanatory variables are irrelevant. Besides, given
that several explanatory variables are included, it is possible that the sign of
some of these variables may seem counter-intuitive, but it should be taken
into consideration that we are comparing them with respect to very particu-
lar cases. That is to say, the group that meets all the omitted characteristics:
men under 45 whose main contribution sector is Industry and Commerce as
well as other aspects.
From 2016 onwards, we project GDP growth, female activity, and informality
rates for 2046 for three macroeconomic scenarios (Table A.3 in the Appendix).
We construct the base scenario under the assumption of a 3% GDP growth
[in line with Güenaga, Mourelle and Vicente (2013) and Dassatti and Mariño
(2014)]: a 2% increase in wages and a 3.5% return rate on constant prices
of the individual savings fund (FAP). Likewise, we assume a gradual reduction
in the labor supply gap between men and women of approximately 20% by
the end of the period with a corresponding informality rate of 21%. The ran-
dom effect is incorporated to the projections by adding a term [
rnormal0,
()
]
to the projection equation that generates a standard random variable with a
0 mean, and is the panel level standard deviation of the regression.8
Individuals’ behavior in the labor market significantly changes by the age of
sixty when retirement becomes an option (at least for those who have met the
contributions requirements). Therefore, it is not sensible to use the projection
8 This term is averaged in over 100 values returned by the rnormal function in order to replicate what
stata does when computing individual random effects.
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
116
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
model described in the previous section for ages over 60. For these ages, we
chose to replicate the evolution of the contribution density observed by gender
and contribution sector for a random sample of 40,000 individuals who were
between 60 and 70 years old in 2016 and apply this evolution to the projected
trajectory for the sample of individuals currently aged 40 to 60 in our sample.
Even if the behavior of individuals from our cohort of interest might change
relative to what has been the behavior of older cohorts from age sixty onwards,
we believe this approach yields a more reasonable evolution than the results
from extending the probit model to older ages.
Administrative records are only available from April 1996 onwards. In order to
compute monthly contributions prior to this date, the social security agency
requires witnesses who can testify that the individual actually worked in a
certain firm in a given time period. To determine the years of contributions
prior to April 1996, we envisage two options: First, we use the information
from the administrative records regarding the start date of the job the indi-
vidual had by April 1996. We assume that since that date the person contrib-
uted without any interruption, and that s/he did not have another formal job
prior to that date. This may underestimate the years of contributions the social
agency will recognize especially for those who were close to forty in 1996 and
can provide witnesses. For this reason, we also consider another option
and choose the maximum years of contributions yielded by the two. The second
option consists of considering the observed contribution density during the
1996-2002 period for each individual and applying that value since the per-
son was 21 years old (age at which the majority of the population entered the
labor market in the nineties according to Household Surveys) until April 1996.
Below we present the contribution projection for the different cohorts (spot-
ted line) up to 70 years old for the base macroeconomic scenario.
B. Income model
In order to estimate individual’s i annual income at time t, we propose a linear
regression model with random effects that includes the following explana-
tory variables: female dummy, five-year age cohorts’ dummies, economic sec-
tor dummies according to ISIC classification, experience, experience squared,
annual income in t -1, and GDP. The estimated income equation is as follows:
YFemaleCohortSectorExperienc e
it ii
ii
t
=+
∝β βββ++
++
1234
Experience GDPIncomeβββε+
5
2
671it titit
++
(2)
Gioia de Melo
et al.
117
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
Figure 2. Projected percentage of individuals contributing to the social security
system by age cohort. Base scenario
0,10
0,30
0,50
0,70
0,90
20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 60 62 64 66 68 70
Cohort 40 to 44 Co hort 45 to 49 Cohort 50 to 54
Cohort 55 to 60 Projection
Ages
Source: Authors´ own computations derived from social security data.
where
it it i
vu=+
, and v
i
is an individual random effect which is constant
through time.
Following Berstein et al. (2006), we define the variable experience as the num-
ber of years contributed at time t. We estimate five separate models, one for
each income quintile.9 Quintiles are calculated considering income between
2013 and 2015 at constant prices. Income is projected solely for those peri-
ods in which it is projected that workers will contribute to the social security
system. Similarly to the contribution projections, for 2016 onwards, the ran-
dom effect is incorporated by adding a term [
rnorma
l0,
()
] to the projection
equation that generates a standard random variable with a 0 mean and when
is the panel level standard deviation of the regression.
9 We initially estimated a single income model including, among other variables, the contributor’s income
quintile for the period 2013-2015. Although this specification showed an appropriate evolution, when
observing the evolution by quintile, the average income of each quintile converged to the average, and
there was a considerable increase in the income of quintile 1 and a decrease in quintile 5.
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
118
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
The figure below shows the evolution (and projection in dotted lines) of income by
gender. It should be noted that the graph considers the evolution of income
only for individuals who continue to contribute to the social security system.
In this sense, the further ahead in time, the fewer individuals continue con-
tributing, and those who do so belong to the younger cohorts and have the
best contribution and income profiles. We present the coefficients of the esti-
mated model for each income quintile in Table A.2 in the Appendix.
Figure 3. Monthly wage projections in the base scenario (2017 average in US dollars)
Year
Total Male Female Projection
0
500
1.000
1.500
2.000
2.500
3.000
3.500
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
2020
2022
2024
2026
2028
2030
2032
2034
Note: The graph considers the evolution of income only for individuals who continue to contribute to
Social Security. The further ahead in time, the fewer individuals continue to contribute and the better
their income profile.
Source: Authors´ own computations derived from social security data.
C. Reconstruction and projection of funds in the
individual savings accounts and annuities
Firstly, for each individual in the sample we reconstruct the history of the
contributions made to the individual account, which depends on the personal
contributions earmarked for this pillar. They are related to each person’s income
level and the choice of voluntary affiliation to the AFAP provided by Article 8
of Law 16,713. As we mentioned before, there is an administration fee charged
by the AFAP, and a collective disability and death insurance premium.
Gioia de Melo
et al.
119
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
The sample contains information about the date of affiliation with the AFAP
for each individual and whether they chose to affiliate under the option pro-
vided by Article 8 of Law 16,713 but does not inform about the administrator
chosen or assigned to them. Using information published by the Central Bank,
we construct an average AFAP of the system (AFAP-System), calculated from
the relative monthly participation of each administrator in the FAP. In this way,
we calculated the average monthly quota of the AFAP-System between 1996-
2005, which reflects the historic average rate of return of the system as well
as the administrative fees paid and disability and death insurance premium.
Based on the information from the BPS administrative records, we compute
the individual’s average gross contribution to the savings pillar and subtract
commissions paid, thus obtaining the net contribution to the FAP. From the
quotient between the net monthly contributions and the average quota value
of the AFAP System, the number of FAP shares (“cuotas”) that are acquired
monthly by each worker are estimated. Thus, when valuing the number of
shares acquired by the worker, at any given time, we obtain the total amount
of savings in the individual account. For the projection, we assume an aver-
age yield of 3.5% measured in indexed price units (UI), which are equivalent
to 1.5% over the evolution of the average wage. We assume that the expected
performance of the accumulation sub-fund is identical to that of the retire-
ment sub-fund.
Figure 4 shows the projected FAP at age 60 for ages in January 2017 (horizon-
tal axis). We can observe the “cohort effect” in relation to the specific situa-
tion within each age subgroup in the sample.
The age bracket in our sample contains individuals who were of different
ages at the time when the multi-pillar system was introduced. This results in
them having a different total number of years’ contribution to their individual
savings accounts. Those close to 60 by January 2017 will have contributed a
maximum of 21 years to their individual savings accounts: on average 80%
less than those in their forties.
Based on the ratio between the FAP estimated at 60 years old and the sum
of gross contributions to the individual, savings accounts at constant values
(updated by the Consumer Price Index), we obtain a measure of the return of
the contributions to this pillar (before paying for administration fees). Accord-
ing to our estimates, the average ratio at 60 years old for the entire sample is
1.33, which implies that, on average at this age, the FAP is 33% higher than
the sum of gross contributions to this pillar.
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
120
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
Figure 4. Projected FAP at age 60 (2017 average in US dollars)
Ages
10.000
15.000
20.000
25.000
30.000
35.000
40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60
60 years old Average 60 years old
Source: Authors´ own computations derived from social security data.
Figure 5 shows that this ratio is increasing with the person’s age. This evolution
indicates that older cohorts benefited to a larger extent from the high rates
of return on Unidades Reajustables (unit value that is periodically adjusted
according to the evolution of wages) registered until 2004, which we do not
expect to recur in the future. This partly compensates for the shorter con-
tribution of older individuals and thereby helps explain the low variation in
replacement rates among cohorts.
According to our estimates, 29% of the cohort under study will never contrib-
ute to the individual savings pillar (AFAP). In turn, those that are expected to
contribute for more than 30 years represent only 13%.
Regarding the calculation of life annuities (RVP for its Spanish acronym), we
use the mortality tables published by the Superintendence of Financial Services,
part of the Central Bank of Uruguay (SSF-BCU), at the beginning of 2017. This
happened at a time during the public consultation on modifications to the indi-
vidual savings scheme promoted by this institution.10 The tables published by
the BCU include the update and dynamization of mortality tables, an increase
10 We chose to use these tables given that they improve the calculation of RVPs compared to those in
use, which were calculated using the 1996 Census.
Gioia de Melo
et al.
121
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
in the reference population, and a better adjustment of the surcharge for the
risk of survival. The update and correction of the probability of generating a
pension for a family member in the event of the death of the RVP holder also
represents an improvement relative to the previous tables. Likewise, for the
calculation of the RVPs, we decided to use the current technical interest rate,
which was set at 1.5% in UR by the SSF-BCU.11
Figure 5. Ratio between FAP at age 60 and gross contributions to individual savings
accounts by age (%)
Ages
40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60
60 years old
1,00
1,05
1,10
1,15
1,20
1,25
1,30
1,35
1,40
1,45
Lineal (60 years old)
Source: Authors´ own computations derived from social security data.
V. Results
A. Years of contributions in the baseline scenario
Table 2 presents the distribution of retirement ages when individuals retire as
soon as they become eligible (immediate retirement), which is our baseline
11 Decree No. 221/017, published on 15 August 2017, eliminated the differentiation by sex in the mortality
tables, and this only allowed differentiation of premiums by age. It is expected that this change will improve
annuities for women as they have a higher life expectancy than men. This effect is likely to exceed the
opposite sign adjustments associated with the probability of generating a pension, the partial (although
limited) effect of which is expected to favor men. However, as stated above, the Mortality Tables that
come from adopting this measure are not yet available, and therefore are not part of this study.
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
122
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
scenario. To present the results in a clearer way, we choose to analyze the
situation of each individual in the sample with respect to their possibilities
of becoming eligible for retirement at three different ages: 60, 65, and 70. An
individual can retire at age 60 (“the normal age”) provided s/he has contrib-
uted for thirty years. If s/he has not done so at 60 years old, but does before
the age of 65, for simplicity we assume s/he will retire at 65. In addition, if
the person has accumulated between 25 and 29 years of contributions at age
65, we assume they retire as part of the old age regime. Furthermore, under
this regime, a person can retire at age 70 if s/he has contributed for between
15 and 24 years. Estimates for years of contributions take into account special
computations and the bonus contribution years per child for women.
Table 2. Distribution of retirement ages in the baseline scenario (%)
Total Men Women Cohort
40 - 44
Cohort
45 - 49
Cohort
50 - 54
Cohort
55 - 60
Quintile
1
Quintile
2
Quintile
3
Quintile
4
Quintile
5
Eligible for retirement at age 60
Normal
age 51.1 52.4 49.8 54.0 50.7 49.1 50.3 19.7 25.3 47.4 73.9 89.4
Eligible for retirement at age 65
Normal
age 5.4 5.5 5.3 6.3 6.7 5.0 3.4 3.0 7.3 9.5 5.7 1.6
Old age 6.3 6.4 6.1 6.1 7.8 6.3 4.8 5.0 9.4 10.1 5.1 1.8
Eligible for retirement at age 70
Old age 8.4 7.7 9.3 5.2 6.7 10.5 12.2 9.4 15.0 11.0 5.2 1.6
Do not become eligible for retirement in the defined benefit scheme
28.7 28.0 29.5 28.5 28.0 29.1 29.3 62.9 42.9 22.0 10.1 5.5
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Note: Calculations in Table 2 refer to our base macroeconomic scenario. Both the optimistic and moderate
macroeconomic scenarios also project that, on average, 51% of the sample will become eligible for retire-
ment at sixty. The main difference by scenario is observed for those who become eligible at 65 years old:
7.2% in the optimistic and 3.9% in the moderate. This is because the projected macroeconomic growth for
2017 onwards would have a greater impact on contribution densities projected at ages above 60 given the
age structure of the sample. Therefore, the percentage of individuals who are not likely to retire from
the PAYG scheme varies from 24.6% in the optimistic scenario to 30.5% in the moderate.
Source: Authors’ own computations based on social security records.
We estimate that 51% of the workers would be able to retire at age 60. This
estimation is higher than that projected by Bucheli et al. (2006, 2010) using
administrative records for the period 1996 – 2004: 38 and 41.3%, respectively.
Gioia de Melo
et al.
123
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
This could be explained by the sustained economic growth, lower unemploy-
ment rate, and decreasing informality rates observed during more recent years,
as well as the bonus for the contribution per child introduced by Law 18,395
in 2008. Indeed, the percentage of workers not contributing to social secu-
rity decreased significantly from 40.7% in 2004 to 24.7% in 2017 (the aver-
age informality rate in the 1996-2004 period considered by previous studies
was 41.1%).
Men exhibit a slightly more favorable prospect in terms of their retirement
although the gender gap seems to have significantly reduced in the last decade
due to both bigger increases in the percentage of women contributing to social
security as well as the 2008 reform that granted women an additional year
of contributions per child (up to five). Also, there is a slightly better situation
for the youngest cohort. On the other hand, we also observe that 28.7% of
our sample would not be eligible for retirement in the PAYG scheme even at
age seventy. About 60% of individuals who are not expected to retire by the
pay-as-you-go scheme will accumulate five years’ contributions or less. These
individuals are likely to be covered by the non-contributory pension although
it currently targets individuals living in households with extremely low income.
B. Replacement rates in the baseline scenario
A pension replacement rate is the defined as the pension entitlement divided
by labor income . It can be defined in several ways, especially depending on
the labor income considered. The most popular measure uses the wage earn-
ings of the year prior to retirement. In this paper, we analyze the ratio consid-
ering two earning periods: average earnings from the last year the individual
worked and their average working life earnings.
Using earnings from the last year worked is more suitable to assess the pension
system’s ability to smooth consumption between working and retirement peri-
ods, which is what a worker would evaluate when deciding whether to retire.
Moreover, this approach enables us to make international comparisons as it
is the most widely used ratio in the literature. In turn, the analysis of replace-
ment rates expressed relative to average earnings throughout the emplo-
yment history provides a better picture of the value of the pension in terms of
the contributions the worker made during his active stage. It should be noted
that this average only comprises periods with positive earnings.
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
124
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
We define the joint replacement rate as the ratio of the sum of the pension
of the PAYG scheme and the annuity received from the individual savings
scheme relative to total labor income for which the worker contributed. The
PAYG rate considers the pension in that pillar in terms of the wage it covers,
and the individual savings’ replacement rate is defined accordingly (annuities
in relation to income devoted to individual saving).
In this section, we show our results in terms of replacement rates in the
immediate retirement scenario discussed in Table 2, section 5.1. In addition to
showing average replacement rates, in Table 3 we include median estimates
to show to what extent average rates are sensitive to extreme values.12 We
include the average contribution density and most frequent earnings quintile
to emphasize that replacement rates at different ages are not comparable as
they involve individuals with very different contribution and income profiles.
Furthermore, it is worth mentioning that the effective replacement rates shown
in this study should not be compared to technical rates used for the calcula-
tion of pensions. This is, firstly, because our replacement rate estimates con-
sider the existence of minimum and maximum pension amounts. Secondly,
it is because when the pension is calculated by the BPS, technical rates are
applied to the average wage earned in the last 10 years, and the maximum of
the average wage earned in the best twenty years is increased by five percent.
Instead, as we already mentioned, to compute effective replacement rates we
consider the ratio between the estimated pension to average earnings from the
last year worked in one case and average working life earnings in the other.
Average replacement rates are significantly affected by extreme values due to
the high incidence of minimum pensions that we estimate 45% of the sample
will receive. At the same time, 23% of those who will receive minimum pen-
sion declare particularly low wages (below the national minimum wage for
44 hours per week). It should be noted that we could not obtain good quality
information on hours worked by the individuals in the sample. The low levels
of declared income have a substantial impact on the averages calculated for
the sample as a whole, which can be seen by comparing the means and medi-
ans of individuals who become eligible at different ages.
12 All tables exclude 1.4% of individuals in the sample that had replacement rates relative to the last
year’s earnings that were above 300%.
Gioia de Melo
et al.
125
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
Table 3. Replacement rates in the baseline scenario (%)
Relative to last
year’s earnings Relative to working life average earnings
Average
contribution
density a
Most
frequent
quintile
Mean Median Mean Median
JointbJoint Joint PAYG
pillar
Individual
savings Joint PAYG
pillar
Individual
savings
Eligible for retirement at age 60
Normal age 51.9 41.3 79 108.4 25.6 61.2 82.8 25.3 0.87 Q 5
Eligible for retirement at age 65
Normal age 61.7 50.3 92.7 131.2 28.3 74.8 107.8 29.3 0.56 Q 3
Old age 68.1 56.2 97.9 133.4 25.5 76.7 106.7 25.4 0.47 Q 3
Eligible for retirement at age 70
Old age 88.7 77.6 116.7 155.6 25.3 95 121.2 24.3 0.39 Q 3
Total 58.6 44.8 86.2 118 25.8 66.1 90.0 25.5 0.75
a Refers to the observed period in the sample: 1996-2015
b Comprises both the pay-as-you-go and the individual savings schemes
Source: Authors’ own computations based on social security records.
On average, those eligible for retirement at age 60 are expected to obtain a
replacement rate of approximately 52% with respect to the average earning
of their last year’s contribution. On the other hand, the replacement rate in
relation to the average salary of the individual’s employment history is 79%.
This is consistent with the fact that wages generally increase throughout
working life, therefore pensions expressed as a ratio of the last year’s earnings
are lower than when expressed as a ratio of working life earnings. Individuals
eligible for retirement at age 60 on average present a high contribution den-
sity (87%) and mainly belong to the fifth income quintile.
The remainder groups that would be eligible for retirement at age 65 and 70
(with lower contribution density and income than those eligible at age sixty)
have higher replacement rates due to both the higher incidence of minimum
pension recipients and the higher technical rates that are applied when indi-
viduals are older at the moment of retirement.
Considering all those individuals who will at some stage be eligible for retire-
ment, and relative to their last year of earnings, average replacement is
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
126
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
estimated at 58.6%, and the median is approximately 45%. Likewise, replace-
ment rates calculated using the average income of working life have an aver-
age of 86% and a median of 66%.
Focusing on the relationship between pensions and average working life earn-
ings, we observe that the replacement rates of the PAYG scheme are on aver-
age above 100% for different ages and regimes (normal age and old age). This
result is strongly influenced by the presence of the minimum pension benefi-
ciaries, which we analyze in a following section. Therefore, those who man-
age to accumulate at least 15 years’ contributions would receive, on average,
a pension above their working life earnings. This may suggest sustainability
challenges that should be analyzed in future research.
Individual savings’ replacement rate estimates are on average 25%. They are
expressed with respect to the wage covered by that pillar over the course of
working life. We do not calculate the replacement rate relative to the last year
of earnings for the individual savings pillar because it may be the case that
workers do not contribute to their individual account during the year prior to
their retirement. When comparing replacement rates for the two pillars, it is
important to bear in mind that while the PAYG pillar also receives contribu-
tions from employers, the funds for individual savings only come from work-
ers. Furthermore, the BPS provides other coverage, such as unemployment
insurance, which does not have a specific financing. Finally, the replacement
rates for the PAYG pillar do not consider the administration costs of the pen-
sion system, which are covered by the fee that AFAPs charge workers in the
case of the individual savings scheme.
Figure 6 is a histogram showing the joint replacement rate (comprises both
PAYG and individuals’ savings pillars) computed in terms of the last year’s
earnings.
Although it is difficult to compare studies across and within countries due to
the different assumptions involved in each exercise, we conclude that Uru-
guayan replacement rates do not seem to differ much from those estimated
for the average of OECD countries and other specific studies available for Chile.
Gioia de Melo
et al.
127
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
Figure 6. Histogram showing joint replacement rates calculated relative to the average
wage in the last twelve months of contributions
0100 200 300
Joint replacement rate
1,00
1,20
1,30
1,45
Density
Source: Authors´ own computations based on social security records.
OECD (2013) estimates a replacement rate of approximately 54% for middle-
income workers of 34 member countries, which to some extent is comparable
to our replacement rate of 51.9% estimated for those eligible for retirement
at age 60 and relative to the last year’s earnings. However, it should be taken
into account that OECD (2013) assumes individuals exhibit continuous con-
tributions for forty years (i.e. no informality or unemployment spans).
According to our estimates, Uruguayan replacement rates that calculated
the last year’s earnings seem to be slightly higher than those computed by
Bernstein et al. (2006) for the average of Chile’s affiliates (44% in relation to
last month’s and the last three years’ wages). As for replacement rates com-
puted using the average working life earnings, according to Berstein et al.
(2006), Chilean replacement rates are estimated at 121%. Chile requires men to
retire at age 65, and the study also considers zero income during periods with-
out contributions when computing average income. Our estimated replacement
rate of 79% at age 60 did not include zero income periods when computing
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
128
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
average working life earnings, but if we did the same, this estimate would
rise to 131%. It should also be taken into account that we only have infor-
mation on wages from 1996 onwards, that is, we lack information on the
older cohorts’ first years of work, and this can result in overestimating aver-
age working life earnings.
Another study on Chile carried out by Paredes and Díaz Fuchs (2013), esti-
mates replacement rates based on average income and pensions rather than
on individual results. In this case, the results for retirement at the legal age
result in an average gross replacement rate of 81%, with respect to working
life earnings for both men and women. This is in line with our estimates for
Uruguay (79% at age 60).
C. Impact of the minimum pensions benefit
According to the social security agency, 28% of the individuals who retired
in 2015 received the minimum pension. It is reasonable to expect this figure
to increase from 2016 onwards as those who contribute to the multi-pillar
system begin to retire. This is due to the high percentage of workers with
income lower than $48.953 (pesos as of January 2017) that voluntarily chose
to assign 50% of their contributions to the individual savings account (Arti-
cle 8, Law 16,713). As such, the amount of contributions to the PAYG pillar
significantly decreased and that makes it more likely for workers to receive a
minimum pension.
By 2017, the minimum contributive pension was $9,930 (approx. US 350
dollars).13 We assume this minimum evolves in line with the variation in real
wages: an increase of 2% per year. According to our projections, minimum
pension recipients would reach 45% of those eligible for retirement (70% of
those expected to receive a minimum pension chose to assign half of their
contributions to the individual savings pillar (Article 8, Law 16713). As men-
tioned before, this has a significant impact on average replacement rates.
Our findings suggest that there is a significant percentage of individuals
who have high contribution densities and a particularly low monthly income
(possibly explained by declaring only a few working days per month), and
13 Established by Decree No. 252/2016: in force since January 1, 2017.
Gioia de Melo
et al.
129
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
who would therefore qualify for a minimum pension. We estimate that 34%
of those who would become eligible for retirement at age 60 would obtain
the minimum amount: this percentage is higher for women (39.7%) than it
is for men (29.3%). This proportion is even higher for those who become eli-
gible for retirement at 65 years old and reaches 84% for those who would
only be able to retire at 70.
According to our estimates, beneficiaries of the minimum pension on average
duplicate the pension they would have received if no minimum existed. None-
theless, the current system of access to minimum pension does not provide
sufficient information to evaluate whether this benefit is targeting the poorest.
Table 4. Minimum pension recipients (%)
Total Men Women
Eligible for retirement at age 60
Normal age 34.1 29.3 39.7
Eligible for retirement at age 65
Normal age 62.1 54.1 71.2
Old age 73.0 66.9 80.1
Eligible for retirement at age 70
Old age 84.1 78.6 89.0
Total 45.0 40.0 52.0
Source: Authors’ own computations based on social security records.
Following Decree 233/017, if we add the annuity derived from the individual
saving accounts to the resulting pension from the PAYG to determine whether
the individual would qualify for a minimum pension, the percentage of indi-
viduals who would receive a minimum pension would drop from 45% to 38%.
However, the average replacement rate remains barely unchanged (58.4%
relative to last year’s earnings and 85.6% relative to average lifetime earn-
ings: compared to 58.6 and 86.2 reported in Table 3). This corresponds to the
fact that the projected amount of annuities for the individuals who would no
longer receive a minimum pension are expected to be very low.
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
130
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
D. Analysis based on socioeconomic characteristics
Table 5 shows the average replacement rates by gender, income quintile, and
contribution sector for individuals who are expected to be eligible for retire-
ment at age 60. Women exhibit lower participation rates and lower wages than
men. These factors have a negative influence on eligibility for retirement and
the expected pension amounts. However, because of the introduction of the
one-year contribution per child scheme and the existence of minimum pen-
sions, the projected replacement rates suggest that women will on average
achieve higher replacement rates than men at the PAYG pillar and, therefore,
also higher joint replacement rates. The computation of pensions in the indi-
vidual savings scheme considers different mortality tables by gender, which
reflects women’s higher life expectancy. This means that, for the same total
savings, women have to finance a longer period of pensions than men, which
results in lower amounts.14
Pensions play a significant redistributive role; with substantially higher replace-
ment rates at lower wage levels. Average rates among quintiles range from
124.8% in Q1 to 33.6% in Q5 relative to the last year’s earnings. These pat-
terns correspond with the significant incidence of minimum pensions in Q1, Q2,
and to a lesser extent Q3. Overall these results show that the PAYG pillar plays
an important redistributive role for those who become eligible for retirement.
According to our estimates, workers in rural and housekeeping sectors have
the highest replacement rates: around 100% relative to the last year’s earn-
ings. Again, this fits with the large percentage of workers from those sec-
tors that will receive a minimum pension when they retire (95% and 76%, in
housekeeping and the rural sector, respectively). We argue that this is both
due to low wages in these sectors and a high percentage of undeclared income
(note that only individuals expected to be eligible for retirement at age 60
are considered in Table 5). Indeed, the Household Survey provides informa-
tion on the percentage of undeclared income: the primary sector and house-
keeping services in 2017 were the sectors that had the highest percentage of
14 The tables used in this study are those published as a proposal by the Central Bank in 2017. However,
in 2018 the Central Bank substituted these tables with a unique table for men and women, removing
the difference in pension amounts due to life expectancy.
Gioia de Melo
et al.
131
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
workers who stated that they did not declare social security for a percentage
of their income.
Overall, replacement rates in the individual savings scheme do not show
substantial differences. Most variation in joint replacement rates for gender,
quintiles, or sectors is explained by differences in the percentage of mini-
mum pension recipients.
Table 5. Replacement rates for those eligible for retirement at age 60 by characteristic
Relative to
last year
earnings
Relative to average lifetime earnings Minimum
pension
recipients (%)
Joint Joint Pay-as-you-go Individual
savings
Total 51.9 79.0 108.4 25.6 34.1
Gender Male 47.5 72.4 99.8 25.8 29.3
Female 57.1 86.6 118.3 25.3 39.7
Income
quintile
Q1 124.8 226.6 288.1 26.4 88.6
Q2 80.4 112.3 156.3 26.5 83.2
Q3 55.3 79.3 112.5 25.8 72.3
Q4 41.6 62.3 86.8 25.4 17.6
Q5 33.6 49.4 69.1 25.3 0.2
Contribution
sector
Industry and
retail 45.8 68.1 95.7 25.1 33.0
Public sector 37.9 54.9 74.0 27.5 5.2
Rural 95.6 161.4 210.0 25.5 75.7
Construction 42.8 61.2 90.6 24.6 28.1
Housekeeping
services 113.3 170.6 229.5 22.2 95.4
Source: Authors’ own computations based on social security records.
Comparing replacement rates by age cohorts is particularly relevant given that
in 2016 the first workers covered by the 1996 reform began to retire. A group
of these workers, who called themselves the “cincuentones” (those in their
fifties), argued that they would receive lower pensions compared to slightly
older workers (not covered by this regime) and to those younger than them
and under the same social security system. This triggered a partial reform in
2017 that allowed the cincuentones to abandon the multi pillar system and
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
132
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
have their pension calculated as 90% of the pension they would have obtained
under the PAYG system, which was in place prior to 1996.
In order to compare replacement rates between different age cohorts, we
believe it is not desirable to express them relative to the average lifetime
working life income because administrative data including income is only
available from 1996 onwards. Therefore, for the older cohorts (ie. those aged
55 – 60 in 2017), we do not consider the income they earned during earlier
stages of their careers. In turn, for those aged between 40 and 44 in 2017 we
are likely to have data that covers almost their whole work history. For this
reason, we consider that the relevant replacement rates that should be com-
pared between different age groups (given the information available) are those
expressed relative to the last year and relative to the average of the wages
earned between age 40 and 60.
Table 6 breaks down average replacement rates by cohorts and quintiles using
the two types of replacement rates. The results show that prospects for those
in their fifties in terms of replacement rates are not that different to those of
younger cohorts with similar income levels (joint replacement rates for those
in Q5 are similar among age cohorts). The reason why we do not find signifi-
cant differences is because even if individual savings replacement rates are
lower for those in their fifties (this cohort had less time to grow their funds
in the individual savings scheme), the PAYG pillar weighs significantly more in
the joint replacement rate and there is no clear pattern between cohorts
in this pillar. Indeed, when comparing replacement rates relative to the last
year’s earnings, older cohorts in Q5 exhibit slightly higher joint replacement
rates due to the PAYG pillar while when replacement rates are computed rela-
tive to wages earned between age 40 and 60, these are slightly lower. Over-
all, we conclude that the individual savings pillar plays a minor role in terms
of its contribution to the joint replacement rates for all the age cohorts that
were analyzed.
E. Sensitivity analysis
Replacement rates under different macroeconomic scenarios show two types of
behavior. On the one hand, when considering the last year’s earnings, replace-
ment rates decrease as macroeconomic conditions improve. This is explained
Gioia de Melo
et al.
133
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
Table 6. Replacement rates at age 60 by cohort and quintile (%)
Age Cohort 40-44 45-49 50-54 55-60
Relative to the last year’s earnings
Quintile 1 91.8 132.7 158.5 124.7
Quintile 2 65.9 75.5 86.5 102.4
Quintile 3 50.7 50.5 59.3 66
Quintile 4 40 40.8 42.2 44.7
Quintile 5 31.5 32.1 34.5 36.2
Total 47.3 50.5 56.4 55.4
Relative to average income 40-60 years old
Joint
Quintile 1 133.2 216.9 267.9 204.5
Quintile 2 91.5 99.4 109.3 115.3
Quintile 3 69.1 68.6 73.3 73.2
Quintile 4 54.9 55.2 54.9 53.1
Quintile 5 43.0 42.8 44.3 42.3
Total 80.6 82.7 84.0 67.7
Pay-as-you-go
Quintile 1 186.4 289.5 335.8 250.4
Quintile 2 137.9 145.9 152.0 148.3
Quintile 3 104.5 100.4 101.5 102.9
Quintile 4 80.3 78.6 77.8 71.7
Quintile 5 62.0 60.6 61.9 61.8
Total 114.5 114.5 111.3 90.4
Individual savings
Quintile 1 24.3 26.2 27.6 18.7
Quintile 2 24.9 24.1 24.1 19.2
Quintile 3 24.3 26.3 23.1 19.2
Quintile 4 29.5 29.7 20.0 15.7
Quintile 5 24.5 22.8 22.1 17.6
Total 30.8 28.0 23.5 17.5
Source: Authors’ own computations based on social security records.
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
134
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
by the fact that wage growth projected towards the end of individuals’ work-
ing lives is higher in the most favourable scenarios. Average rates decline by
about eight percentage points, from an average of 64% in the moderate sce-
nario to 58.6% and 56.6% in the base and optimistic scenarios, respectively.
In terms of replacement rates in relation to average working life earnings, we
observe the opposite behaviour. That is, they grow under the most favourable
scenarios, implying a greater correlation between contributions over the entire
working life and the resulting retirement. Average rates in the extreme sce-
narios increase 10 percentage points from 82.9% to 92.2% and from 64.6%
to 69.5%. In these scenarios, we also estimated the number of people receiv-
ing minimum retirement benefits, assuming a minimum retirement growth of
3% and 1%, respectively for the optimistic scenario and moderate scenarios.
In the moderate scenario, we estimated that 41% of the individuals eligible
for retirement would receive the minimum pension, while 49% would do so
in the optimistic scenario. Overall the main conclusions remain unchanged.
As a robustness check, we calculate replacement rates under the assumption
that individuals’ income from 2016 onwards grows at an annual rate of 2%
in real terms (provided they continue contributing to the social security sys-
tem); thus, we ignore the income model described in Section 4.2. Replace-
ment rates do not differ significantly from those reported in Table 3 (they are
slightly higher relative to the last year’s earnings but slightly lower relative to
working life earnings). Under this scenario, 47% of those eligible for retire-
ment would receive a minimum pension.
We calculated the effect of a one percentage point decrease in the variable
administrative fee charged by the AFAPs on the individual saving accounts
replacement rate and an increase of one percentage point in the rate of return
of the Fondo de Ahorro Previsional (FAP). The base macroeconomic scenario
was applied in both cases.
We estimate that a reduction of one percentage point in the administration
fee charged by the AFAPs will have a positive effect of 0.9 percentage points
on the rate obtained by this pillar, while an increase in the rate of return
of the same magnitude will increase the replacement rate by 2.4 percent-
age points. The limited effects estimated can be explained by the age profile
of the cohort analyzed, for whom the potential effects of these parametric
changes have a short-term impact: i.e. the last years of their work history. As
Gioia de Melo
et al.
135
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
expected, when analyzing the results after splitting them by smaller cohorts,
we can see that the younger workers have been impacted the most by these
exercises. A decrease in one percentage point in the administration fee the
younger members of the sample were charged would imply an average increase
in the replacement rate of 1.5 percentage points at age 60. Furthermore,
an increase of equal magnitude in the projected rate of return would result in an
increase in the replacement rate of 4 percentage points.
F. Replacement rates in the deferral scenario
In this section we estimate the effect the replacement rates have on decid-
ing to postpone retirement for five years under the baseline macroeconomic
scenario. We did this for a subgroup (43.6% of the sample) that is expected
to have accumulated at least 30 years’ contributions at age 60 and for whom
the contribution model projected they would continue to contribute at least
until age 65. The results are presented in the table below.
Table 6. Comparison of replacement rates between immediate retirement at age
sixty and deferred retirement until age 65
Relative to last year earnings
Mean Median
Total Men Women Total Men Women
Chooses to retire at 60
Joint 50.5 46.7 55.0 40.6 39.9 41.6
Chooses to retire at 65
Joint 57.6 54.1 61.7 51.1 50.7 51.4
Relative to working life average earnings
Chooses to retire at 60
PAYG pillar 106.5 98.8 115.6 81.1 79.2 84.5
Individual savings 26.0 26.2 25.8 25.7 26.4 25.0
Joint 77.8 72.2 84.5 60.6 59.0 63.2
Chooses to retire at 65
PAYG pillar 125.8 119.3 133.5 105.5 103.7 108.1
Individual savings 38.5 38.8 38.1 38.1 39.1 36.8
Joint 93.2 88.3 99.0 80.8 79.2 82.8
Source: Authors’ own computations based in social security records.
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
136
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
We estimate that the joint replacement rate measured with respect to the
income of the last 12 months would increase on average by approximately 7
percentage points if retirement was postponed for five years (increasing from
50.5% to 57.6%).
The decision to continue working results in an average increase in pensions
of 41% in real terms. However, the subgroups’ labor income is also projected
to increase in real terms during those years (18% in real terms). This attenu-
ates the increase of the replacement rate calculated using the last year’s earn-
ings. Within this subgroup of individuals with a high contribution density, it
is expected that 29.8% would receive the minimum pension if they retired at
age 60, whereas if they postponed their retirement until age 65, this percent-
age would be reduced to 18%.
With regard to the replacement rate measured in terms of the average income
of the individuals’ employment history, the joint rate would increase by 15
percentage points from 77.8% to 93.2%. That is, if individuals who accumu-
late at least 30 years’ contributions at age 60 continued to work until age
65, they would have a replacement rate of almost the average income earned
during their working life.
Individual savings´ replacement rates under a scenario where individuals post-
pone their retirement until age 65 are estimated at 38.5%. This is in line with
rates computed by Durán and Pena (2011) for Uruguay using household surveys.
Overall, our results suggest that the PAYG pillar has only mild incentives to
defer retirement. This is not only related to technical rates but also to the
incidence of minimum pensions. Alvarez et al. (2010) suggest incentives for
postponing retirement are low compared to advanced economies. Also, Cama-
cho (2016) argues that the premia added to technical replacement rates for
each additional year of service relative to the minimum required for a given
age (0.5%) is insufficient from a financial-actuarial perspective. It should be
mentioned that while in Uruguay technical replacement rates increase by 3
percentage points for every additional year of deferred retirement (and addi-
tional year of contribution) in the PAYG pillar, pensions increase by 10.4 per-
centage points in the United Kingdom, 8.4 percentage points in Japan, and 8
percentage points in the United States (OECD, 2013).
Gioia de Melo
et al.
137
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
VI. Conclusions
In this paper, we estimate eligibility for retirement and replacement rates of
the Multi-Pillar security system in Uruguay for a cohort of salaried workers
using a random sample of individual social security records.
The main results in terms of access to the contributive system show that there
is a significant degree of polarization: while approximately half of the cohort
would become eligible for retirement in the PAYG pillar at 60 years old, almost
30% would not be able to retire even at age 70. Most of the latter are expected
to accumulate less than five years’ contributions in their working life.
With regard to the adequacy of benefits, although we acknowledge the dif-
ficulty of making international comparisons, we believe that our estimated
joint replacement rate for the multi-pillar system at age 60 with respect to
last year’s earnings (52%) is comparable to the OECD’s average (54%), accord-
ing to OECD (2013), and higher than the minimum suggested by ILO (40%). It
is important to consider that pensions in Uruguay are indexed exclusively to
wage inflation, while according to OECD (2013) most countries do so relatively
to consumer price inflation. Thereby, two countries with similar replacement
rates at the moment of retirement may exhibit divergent trajectories if com-
pared years after retirement.
Although our results indicate significant differences by income quintiles in
terms of access to the contributive system, once individuals are eligible for
retirement the system has a marked distributive profile. The existence of a
minimum pension and the very recognition of years of contributions per child
generate an important redistributive effect on the transition from active to
passive life, which is shown by high replacement rates in the PAYG pillar for
the lower quintiles. In future research, it would be interesting to assess the
overall impact of the pensions system on inequality.
Our finding that 45% of those eligible for retirement would receive a mini-
mum pension also points to the relevance of addressing challenges regard-
ing informality both in terms of the percentage of workers who contribute to
social security and the amounts they declare. It should be highlighted that this
finding could only be obtained thanks to the use of individual administrative
records. The fact that for a relatively important part of workers the declared
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
138
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
income is smaller than the minimum wage suggests the need to revisit the
contribution incentives according to actual labor income. Also, minimum pen-
sions imply implicit subsidies to the PAYG pillar that should be quantified and
their ability to target poverty assessed. Eventually, the role of the contributive
and non-contributive pillars should be revised.
Overall, our results suggest that the PAYG pillar’s incentives to defer retire-
ment are mild. In the same vein, Alvarez et al. (2010) and Camacho (2016) have
pointed out challenges regarding incentives to postpone retirement because
of the current technical replacement rates. As for the individual savings pil-
lar, we conclude that this pillar plays a minor role in terms of its contribution
to the joint replacement rates. This is not only the case for older workers who
contributed to the multi-pillar system for a few years but also for younger
workers whose entire work history is covered by it.
When comparing results by age cohorts, we conclude that there are no sig-
nificant differences between the average joint replacement rates estimated
for individuals currently aged 49 and those aged 50-60, even when we break
down the results by income quintiles. This discussion is particularly relevant
for policy issues since, in 2017, a law was passed to allow the “cincuen-
tones” to be subject to conditions similar to those prevailing prior to the
1996 reform. In practice, the implemented changes delay the maturation of
the multi-pillar system and just perpetuate the previous regime the solvency
of which was questioned; thus, higher financial pressure was imposed on
the system.
This study analyzes coverage and retirement-income adequacy of the Uru-
guayan social security system. Some of the estimations in this paper rein-
force the ever-present need to assess the sustainability of the PAYG pillar in
the medium term. In this sense, our finding that average replacement rates
in this pillar relative to average working life earnings exceed 100% is a mat-
ter of concern. Analyzing the sustainability of the pension system should be
addressed in future work as Uruguay has reached almost full coverage if both
contributory and non-contributory schemes are considered and demographic
tensions are expected to become even more challenging in the future. Indeed,
the analysis of the sustainability of pension systems is likely to become part
of a global research agenda as many countries are beginning to face similar
demographic challenges.
Gioia de Melo
et al.
139
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
Acknowledgments
This study was coordinated by Centro de Estudios Fiscales (CEF) and counted
on the participation of professionals from the Ministerio de Economía y Finan-
zas and the Ministerio de Trabajo y Seguridad Social. It did not require addi-
tional funding.
We are particularly thankful to the two anonymous reviewers for their com-
ments and suggestions as well as for the technical support received by the
Inter-American Development Bank (IDB). We are also grateful for advice
received from Javier Alejo, Marcelo Bérgolo, Mariano Bosch, Rodrigo Ceni,
Álvaro Forteza, Matías Giacobasso, Andrés Masoller as well as from seminar
participants at the Facultad de Ciencias Económicas y de Administración, the
Inter-American Development Bank, and the Banco Central del Uruguay. Finally,
we are very thankful to the Banco de Previsión Social for providing access to
the data used in this study. All errors are our own.
References
1. Álvarez, I., Silva, N., Forteza, A., & Rossi, I. (2010). ¿Qué incentivos al
retiro genera la seguridad social? El caso uruguayo. Latin American
Journal of Economics, 47(136), 217-247.
2. Altamirano, A., Berstein, S., Bosch, M., García-Huitrón, M., & Oliveri, M.
(2018). Presente y futuro de las pensiones en América Latina y el Caribe.
Monografía del BID, 649. Retrieved from: https://publications.iadb.org/
es/presente-y-futuro-de-las-pensiones-en-america-latina-y-el-caribe
3. Bernstein, S., Larrain, G., & Pino, F. (2006). Chilean pension reform:
Coverage facts and policy alternatives. Economía, 6(2), 227-279.
4. Bucheli, M., Ferreira-Coimbra, N., Forteza, A., & Rossi, I. (2006). El acceso
a la jubilación o pensión en Uruguay: ¿Cuántos y quiénes lo lograrían?
Comisión Económica para América Latina y el Caribe (CEPAL). Serie
Estudios y Perspectivas. Oficina de CEPAL, Montevideo. Retrieved from:
https://www.cepal.org/es/publicaciones/5157-acceso-la-jubilacion-o-
pensiones-uruguay-cuantos-quienes-lo-lograrian
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
140
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
5. Bucheli, M., Forteza, A., & Rossi, I. (2010). Work histories and the Access
to contributory pensions: The case of Uruguay. Journal of Pension
Economics and Finance, 9(3), 369-391.
6. Camacho, L. (2016). Análisis global sobre posibles cambios paramétricos
del régimen de reparto administrado por el Banco de Previsión Social.
Banco de Previsión Social. Retrieved from: https://www.bps.gub.uy/bps/
file/11120/1/52.-analisis-global-sobre-posibles-cambios-parametricos-
del-regimen-de-reparto.-bps.-lcamacho.pdf
7. Castañeda, P., Castro, R., Céspedes, L., & Fajnzylber, E. (2013). Estudio
sobre la Sustentabilidad del Fondo de Reserva de Pensiones. Dirección
de Presupuesto, Gobierno de Chile. Santiago de Chile.
8. Dassatti, C., & Mariño, N. (2014). Maduración del sistema previsional:
proyecciones y agenda (Documento de Trabajo Nº 003-2014, ISSN
1668-7565). Banco Central del Uruguay. Retrieved from: https://www.
bcu.gub.uy/Comunicaciones/Jornadas%20de%20Economa/t_dassatti_
cecilia_2014.pdf
9. Durán Valverde, F., & Pena, H. (2011). Determinantes de las tasas de
reemplazo de pensiones de capitalización individual: escenarios latino-
americanos comparados. Comisión Económica para América Latina y el
Caribe (CEPAL). División de Desarrollo Social. Serie Nº 64. Santiago de
Chile. Retrieved from: https://www.cepal.org/es/publicaciones/7020-de-
terminantes-tasas-reemplazo-pensiones-capitalizacion-individual-es-
cenarios
10. Forteza, A., & Ourens, G. (2012). Redistribution, insurance and incen-
tives to work in Latin American pension programs. Journal of Pension
Economics and Finance, 11(03), 337-364.
11. Forteza, A., & Sanroman, G. (2015). Social security and retirement in
Uruguay. Journal of Development Studies, 51(4), 386-406.
Gioia de Melo
et al.
141
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
12. Forteza, A., & Rossi, I. (2016). La jubilación de los “cincuentones” (Docu-
mento de Trabajo). Departamento de Economía de la Facultad de Ciencias
Sociales (DECON). Universidad de la República. Retrieved from: http://
cienciassociales.edu.uy/departamentodeeconomia/wp-content/uploads/
sites/2/2016/07/0316.pdf
13. Güenaga, M., Mourelle, J., & Vicente, L. (2013). Estimaciones alterna-
tivas de producto potencial y brecha de producto en Uruguay. La función
de producción versus filtros univariados. Banco Central del Uruguay.
Retrieved from: http://www.bcu.gub.uy/Comunicaciones/Jornadas%20
de%20Economa/t_mourelle_jos%C3%A9_2013_1527.pdf
14. Lavalleja, M., Rossi, I., & Tenenbaum, V. (2018). La flexibilización de
las condiciones de acceso a las jubilaciones en el Uruguay. Comisión
Económica para América Latina y el Caribe (CEPAL). Serie Estudios
y Perspectivas. Oficina de la Cepal en Montevideo. Retrieved from:
https://www.cepal.org/es/publicaciones/43250-la-flexibilizacion-condi-
ciones-acceso-jubilaciones-uruguay
15. OECD. (2013). Pensions at a Glance 2013, OECD and G20 Indicators. OECD
Publishing. doi: 10.1787/19991363.
16. Paredes, R., & Díaz Fuchs, D. (2013). Pensiones y tasas de reemplazo
generadas por el sistema de AFP en Chile. Retrieved from: https://www.
aafp.cl/wp-content/uploads/2016/05/Tasas-de-Reemplazo-Pensiones-
de-Vejez_2012-Informe-Final.pdf
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
142
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
Appendix
Table A.1 Contribution model (probability to make monthly contributions). Model
coefficients for the observed period 1996-2015
Female -0.601***
(0.034)
Accumulated density 3.832***
(0.006)
45 to 49 Cohort 0.049**
(0.021)
50 to 54 Cohort 0.093***
(0.022)
55 to 60 Cohort 0.189***
(0.023)
Public 0.789***
(0.026)
Rural 0.116***
(0.024)
Construction -0.160***
(0.032)
Housekeeping Services. 0.074**
(0.032)
Age 0.017***
(0.001)
Age^2 0.000***
(0.000)
GDP 0.010***
(0.000)
Informality rate 0.003***
(1.080)
Female participation rate 0.013***
(0.001)
Female participation rate*Female 0.013***
(0.001)
Constant -3.876***
(0.053)
Observations 3,352,852
Numbers of individuals 14,207
Standard errors in parenthesis *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1*
Gioia de Melo
et al.
143
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
Table A.2. Income model. Estimated coefficients for each quintile
Quintile1 Quintile2 Quintile3 Quintile4 Quintile5
Female 1,238** -6.255 47.16 -1,596 -5,903**
(575.1) (723.0) (809.4) (990.7) (2,456)
Last year earnings 0.630*** 0.643*** 0.694*** 0.759*** 0.934***
(0.00569) (0.00503) (0.00409) (0.00329) (0.00205)
45 to 49 Cohort -1,605** -1,688* 284.9 -2,344** 18,683***
(713.0) (875.2) (952.0) (1,186) (3,556)
50 to 54 Cohort -1,348* -1,156 -627.6 -3,764*** 37,055***
(726.2) (935.3) (1,062) (1,345) (4,031)
55 to 60 Cohort -1,015 -202.9 805.0 377.3 61,945***
(757.8) (1,003) (1,153) (1,571) (4,826)
Agro, Forest, Fishing, and Mines -7,448*** -9,446*** -7,742*** -14,248*** -2,655
(1,469) (1,654) (1,785) (1,867) (7,187)
Manufacturing Ind. 909.1 -5,616*** -6,093*** -9,697*** -3,380
(1,718) (1,775) (1,815) (1,509) (3,771)
Electricity, gas and water -1,649 -5,743** -8,717** -13,642* 16,734***
(2,082) (2,419) (3,540) (7,645) (5,643)
Construction -1,687 -11,239*** -8,459*** -12,495*** -32,009***
(1,651) (1,913) (1,989) (1,821) (7,078)
Commerce, Restaurants, and
Hotels -326.5 -5,806*** -7,212*** -12,107*** -462.6
(1,541) (1,623) (1,695) (1,419) (4,135)
Transport and Communication. 1,889 -2,089 -3,517* -10,196*** -4,146
(2,056) (2,111) (2,067) (1,740) (3,945)
Financial intermediation,
insurance. -5,468*** -3,888* -6,124*** -14,306*** -6,265
(1,909) (2,127) (2,272) (2,194) (5,602)
Administrative Act. 1,227 -2,448 -6,633*** -10,585*** 15,875
(2,081) (2,245) (2,484) (3,277) (11,123)
Education -135.7 -1,106 -3,187 -7,683*** 4,027
(2,594) (2,693) (2,664) (2,367) (5,143)
(Continued)
Eligibility for retirement and replacement rates in the Uruguayan
144
DESARRO. SOC. 83, BOGOTÁ, SEGUNDO SEMESTRE DE 2019, PP. 105-144, ISSN 0120-3584, E-ISSN 1900-7760, DOI: 10.13043/DYS.83.3
Table A.2. Income model. Estimated coefficients for each quintile
Quintile1 Quintile2 Quintile3 Quintile4 Quintile5
Health 1,217 1,707 994.2 1,024 15,370***
(2,171) (2,493) (2,438) (2,043) (3,738)
Arts and others -175.1 -8,846*** -5,003** -7,724*** -15,680**
(1,906) (2,156) (2,343) (2,420) (7,727)
Home Serv. -3,068** -6,935*** -9,797*** -21,762*** -
(1,492) (1,760) (2,420) (5,470)
Extraterritorial Org. - - - -59,879*** -70,489
(22,143) (58,349)
GDP 278.5*** 461.9*** 677.2*** 993.0*** 1,554***
(9.245) (12.34) (14.46) (19.56) (52.79)
Experience 577.4*** 755.3*** 832.6*** 926.5*** -2,642***
(94.54) (136.9) (152.3) (191.4) (471.4)
Experience^2 -23.99*** -25.62*** -30.81*** -41.10*** -46.36***
(3.070) (4.759) (4.879) (5.594) (12.11)
Constant -20,640*** -25,418*** -41,298*** -55,582*** -91,735***
(1,946) (2,312) (2,583) (2,872) (7,783)
The cohort of 40 to 44 and Public Administration are omitted. Age is calculated as of January 2017.
Standard errors in parenthesis *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1
Source: Authors’ own calculations based on social security records.
Table A.3. Macroeconomic Scenarios (%)
Macroeconomic Scenarios
Variables Moderate Base Optimistic
GDP growth 1. 5 3.0 4.5
Real Wage growth 1.0 2.0 3.0
Female participation rate in 2046a56 59 64
Informality rate in 2046a30 21 15
FAP return in Unidades Indexadasb3.5 3.5 3.5
a According to calculations from the Household Survey, the participation rate of women in January 2016
was 57% and the percentage of individuals who did not contribute to social security was 23.8% in the
same period.
b Unit of value that is adjusted with the evolution of consumer prices.
Source: Authors’ own calculations based on social security records.

VLEX utiliza cookies de inicio de sesión para aportarte una mejor experiencia de navegación. Si haces click en 'Aceptar' o continúas navegando por esta web consideramos que aceptas nuestra política de cookies. ACEPTAR